However,
this has been a slow and difficult task due to the popularity of
cigarettes, their addictive nature and the power of tobacco
companies. Compared with other risks, however, the ones posed by
cigarettes are easy to control, as
Beck illustrates.
To begin with, the cost of regulation is relatively cheap.
Environmental risks, in comparison, are potentially devastating but
the price to solve the problem is often too great to warrant action.
Secondly, the reach of other risks are global, and as such, difficult
to tackle without international co-operation. Thirdly, cigarettes are
not as integrated into our lives as mobile phones for instance. We
might find these a lot more difficult to regulate if they are found
to pose serious health risks. Finally, the health threats caused by
cigarettes are indisputable, even by pro-tobacco lobbyists.
Sometimes,
experts disagree with other experts on matters of grave importance.
A no-win situation may be presented to the minister tasked with
enforcing regulation when the jury is hung as to whether a risk
exists at all. They may declare a risk so that the public is saved
from the hazard. But, if the risk is later found to be baseless, the
minister could be accused of scaremongering. On the other hand, if
the minister, supported by the opposing camp of scientists, reassures
the public that the risk is negligible and things turn out otherwise,
not only do they face the consequence of the hazard, they may also be
accused of a cover-up.

The
regulation of cigarettes is a good illustration of notions of
technological risk, choice and control, ideas introduced by writers
such as Anthony
Giddens.
Advances in science and technology have given us an unprecedented
abundance of choice, without which, according to Giddens, we would
not feel the effects of risk quite so painfully. Due to liberation
from traditional pathways we are confronted by choice from the moment
we wake up. Should you eat bacon and eggs for breakfast or muesli and
yoghurt? Should you drive or take the train? Should you work in an
office or a factory? Should you light a cigarette or abstain?
Unfortunately, you now know that these choices are laden with risk,
and without God, the devil or sin or any other external source to
which you may attribute blame for the evils of the world, the weight
of the decision lies firmly on your shoulders. This is a process
Ulrich
Beck calls
individualization which heightens our sense of risk. Smoking
cigarettes is now a risky business, not for the dangers it entails,
which remain the same, but for the way its dangers are perceived.

According
to Giddens, our sense of risk is "bound up with the aspiration
to control and particularly with the idea of controlling the future"
which further compounds our sense of risk by creating material
man-made dangers. The paradox is that we often turn to technology,
further control, to save us from these dangers, which in turn creates
its own risks. For instance, while nuclear power reduces the risk of
producing carbon emissions and using unsustainable resources through
burning fossil fuels, its own risks have been powerfully demonstrated
by events such as the
Chernobyl disaster (1986),
the
Three Mile Island accident (1979) and
the more recent Fukushima
Daiichi nuclear disaster (2011). We
have become trapped in a self-reflexive loop where the control of one
risk results in the generation of a new one.
While
the regulation of cigarettes may seem benign in comparison, it is a
solution to a technological problem which may bring about its own set
of risks such as infringement of liberty for smokers, an increase in
cigarettes on the black market, loss of tax revenue to the government
and an increase in pension expenditure as the population ages. From
this perspective, the desire to regulate cigarettes is itself borne
out of a dangerous cultural addiction to control. Is there a solution
to this? Or are we caught in an inescapable paradox where any attempt
to fix our situation exacerbates it?
No comments:
Post a Comment